Congestion Pricing - Links to Congestion Pricing Home

Interstate 75 Stated Preference Survey
Final Report

Printable Version (PDF 2443KB)

CONTENTS:

  

Documentation Methods

The following is technical documentation of the methods used to conduct the Interstate 75 Stated Preference (SP) Survey for the Georgia State Road and Tollway Authority (SRTA).

QUESTIONNAIRE

NuStats and Mark Bradley collaboratively designed the survey instrument with input from the State Road and Tollway Authority, the Georgia Department of Transportation and other members of the project team. Upon approval of the instrument it was programmed into a computer-assisted telephone interviewing (CATI) environment for dialing. The questionnaire contained 179 data items and four screener questions to confirm the eligibility of respondents for participation in the survey.

DATA COLLECTION

Survey specialists under contract to NuStats, conducted pilot data collection for the survey from 5:30 PM to 8 PM CST on July 14, 2005. All survey specialists attended a training session and were required to perform simulated interviews before beginning actual data collection activities. In addition, interviewers were continually monitored to ensure that the highest level of quality was maintained. The pilot was dialed in English only.

A total of 30 completed surveys were collected during the pilot data collection phase utilizing computer-assisted telephone interviewing (CATI) software. The use of CATI interviewing was essential to the research process to ensure that the right information was collected in the most efficient manner. The average length of each completed pilot survey was 14 minutes. Upon reviewing the pilot data and consulting with both interviewers and survey leads, a few minor revisions were made to the instrument to streamline data collection. Upon approval from the client, dialing for the full study began on July 15, with the pilot completes counting toward the ultimate goal of 1,500 completed surveys. The last of the contractually required completes was obtained on September 3, 2005. The final survey length was 12.9 minutes. It should be noted that the data collection was split equally (750-surveys each) between the summer (7/14/05 to 8/14/05) and autumn (8/15/05 to 9/3/05).

EDIT CHECKS

Prior to any data analysis, NuStats performed a comprehensive edit check for each completed interview. During this phase, each interview was required to pass a routine edit check program before it could be included in the final data set. Routine edit checks include such items as data range limitations, skip patterns, logic checks and coding of open end responses.

SURVEY POPULATION

The population of inference (or population under study) for the SRTA SP Survey consists of individuals 18 years of age or older, residing within the I-75/575 survey sampling areas (see Technical Sampling),who travel the target segment at least once per week. Eligible respondents also had at least one vehicle available for use by members of the household.

SAMPLE SIZES, TARGETS AND QUOTAS

A total of 1,500 valid interviews were required to meet project objectives. Of these, 750 were completed in summer 2005 and 750 were completed in autumn 2005. Quotas were established to ensure this equal seasonal distribution. Quotas were also established to obtain 70 percent of trips in the peak periods (AM peak is defined as 6 AM to 10 AM, and PM peak is defined as 3 PM to 7 PM) and 30 percent all other times including Saturday and Sunday.

At the onset of the survey, it was estimated that approximately 75% (1,125 interviews) would be conducted with drivers of single occupancy vehicles (SOV) who would be respondents for the SP questions on willingness to pay and potential use of priced facilities. Upon completion of the survey, it was observed that 73% of interviews were conducted with drivers of SOVs.

SAMPLING FRAME GENERATION

The sampling frame initially consisted of listed (known residential address) and unlisted (no known residential address) telephone numbers for households located in the I-75/575 sampling area (total of 150 census tracts - see technical sampling memorandum). Upon completion of summer data collection, it was noted that dialing productivity was not sufficient to maintain the project budget or schedule. As such, the summer data was analyzed and no statistically significant differences were noted between surveys captured with listed and unlisted sample. Furthermore, the productivity of the listed sample was significantly better than unlisted sample. As such, the project team decided to exclusively dial listed telephone numbers for the remainder of data collection, which included all of the autumn season.

The sample was ordered proportional to pre-defined census tract aggregations defined in the technical sampling memorandum. A total of 16,179 sample records were received for dialing in the SRTA SP survey, of which 12,092 (75%) had address information and 4,087 (25%) had no address information1s. All sample was procured from Marketing Systems Group (MSG) based in Fort Washington, PA.

SAMPLE PREPARATION

The sample was prepared for administration by partitioning it into 51 subsamples (or replicates) of approximately 315 records each. A replicate is a systematically selected subsample of a sample that is geographically representative of the entire sample; the primary benefit of which is that the interviewers did not need to contact the entire sample in order to ensure proper representation. These replicates were released sequentially over the field period.

SURVEY RATES

Table 1 below provides a description of the final dispositions of the 12,692 sample pieces that were used during the I-75/575 SP survey. As indicted in the table, the final response rate was 47% and the final refusal rate was 15%.

Table 1. Final Dispositions

Label Count %
Answering Machine 2,065 16%
Busy 179 1%
Complete 1,501 12%
Disconnect 1,669 13%
Business/Government 509 4%
Language Barrier/Deaf 269 2%
Fax/Modem 686 5%
Caller ID 2 0%
Not Qualified 2,019 16%
Over Quota 21 0%
Specific Callback, Respondent 12 0%
General Callback, Household 222 2%
No Answer 873 7%
Partial Complete 2 0%
1st Refusal 1,226 10%
Hang Up 1,179 9%
Hard, Final Refusal 234 2%
Hard Refusal (Conversion Attempt) 24 0%
Total 12,692 100%
empty cell All Sample
Sample Pieces Used 12,692 empty cell
Completed Surveys 1,501 12%
HHlds eligible for participation 1,761 empty cell
Ineligible sample 5,175 41%
Sample still working 5,756 empty cell
Ratio of good to bad sample 25.39% empty cell
Expected eligible sample to come 1,461 empty cell
Official Response Rate 46.58% empty cell
Refusal Rate 14.65% empty cell
Ratio of CM to Eligible 85.24% empty cell
Average Interview Length 12.90 Minutes

Back to Table of Contents

Stated Preference Analysis

SRTA STATED PREFERENCE RESULTS

Stated preference questions were used to measure respondents’ likelihood of using the HOT lanes as a function of the toll level and time savings. The questions were asked of 1,089 respondents whose reference trip was made as a SOV driver on I-75/575. The introduction and wording of the questions is shown below.

Now assume you’re making a future trip on I-75 just like the one that you just told me about. It’s a trip on the same day, at the same time of day, for the same purpose, and you’re under the same time pressures. You are traveling on the segment of I-75 between I-285 and I-575 and have the option of using the new carpool lane if you want to.

Order A: If you were to use the general traffic lanes on this segment of I-75, your trip would take TT+[#] and be free. If you used the new carpool lane as a single driver you would pay [$] and your trip would take TT, saving [#] minutes. You could also choose to carpool with someone and use the lane for free. Now under these conditions, would you choose to:

Use the carpool lane, pay [$] and save [#] minutes 1
Use the general lane for free 2
Carpool with someone to use the carpool lane for free 3
DK 98

Order B: If you were to use the carpool lane on this segment of I-75 as a single driver, you would pay [$] and your trip would take TT. If you were to use the general traffic lanes, your trip would take TT+[#], [#] minutes longer than in the toll lane, but it would be free. You could also choose to carpool with someone to use the carpool lane for free. Now under these conditions, would you choose to:

Use the general lane for free 2
Use the carpool lane, pay [$] and save [#] minutes 1
Carpool with someone to use the carpool lane for free 3
DK 98

SP METHOD A

Each person received 4 different scenarios of this type, each with a different amount of time savings (# = 5, 10, 15 or 20 minutes) and toll ($ = 50 cents, $1, $2, $3, $4, $5, $6 or $7). The value TT used for the tolled lane was based on the respondent’s estimate of their travel time with no congestion. Nine different sets of 4 scenarios were used across the sample, with each respondent assigned 1 of the 9 sets at random. So, in total, 36 (9 x 4) different scenarios were used, each identifying a different time/cost tradeoff point.

To avoid bias due to ordering effects, the questions were asked in two different ways. Versions Order A and Order B above differ only in the order in which the toll and non-toll options are described to the respondent. Each respondent was randomly assigned one of the two orders for all SP questions.

In the cases where respondents chose option 3, Carpool, they were asked to imagine that it would not have been possible for them to carpool for that trip, and to choose from one of the two remaining options, 1 or 2.

SP METHOD B

Next, the same type question was asked again, but this time using the “price meter” approach. Each respondent was assigned a level of time savings (S = 5, 10 or 15 minutes) at random. Then a random toll price point was chosen (P = 50 cents, $1, $2, $3, $4, $5, $6 or $7) and the same question from above was asked (Order A or Order B). If the person said that they would pay the toll, a higher price point was chosen at random, and if they said they would not pay the toll, a lower price point was chosen at random, and the question was asked again at the new toll level. This procedure was continued until the “switching point” was identified – e.g. the respondent would be willing to pay a toll of $2, but not willing to pay the next higher level, $3.

Note that this method is designed to obtain the same type of information as from a “transfer price” question which would ask each respondent directly how much they would be willing to pay for the given time savings. There are, however, drawbacks to the transfer price approach, in that respondents tend to find it much more difficult to answer such a direct question than to provide simpler yes or no type answers to specific time and toll combinations. So, we designed Method B to approximate the type of information that would be obtained from a transfer price question, but using simple pairwise choices with EXACTLY the same questionnaire wording as used in Method A. So, to the respondent, the Method B questions were simply a continuation of the Method A questions, and thus not likely to be answered in any significantly different way, and thus not much more prone to policy bias than the Method A responses.

Figure 1. Percent Willing to Pay Toll

PERCENT WILLING TO PAY TOLL

Figure 1 shows the percent of respondents who said they would pay the toll and use the HOT lane under each different level of time savings and toll. The Method A questions identify 22 different time/cost trading points, while the Method B questions represent 24 different time/cost trading points. Thus, both methods provide roughly the same amount of tradeoff information.

In Figure 1, there are 7 lines, 4 from Method A at 5, 10, 15 and 20-minute time savings, and 3 from Method B (the “price meter” approach) at 5, 10 and 15 minute time savings. The results appear to be consistent and reasonable. Some key findings are described below.

The two methods give consistent results. The lines for 5, 10 and 15 minutes for Method A track the corresponding lines from Method B quite well. The price meter (Method B) approach gives somewhat smoother curves and lower values.

Even at a very low toll level (50 cents) not everyone is willing to pay it. Only about 40% would pay that much for a 5-minute savings, while about 65% would pay it to save 10 minutes and 75% would pay it to save 15 minutes.

Even at fairly high toll levels above $3, a small fraction would be willing to pay for any level of time savings. This result supports the typical finding that there is a wide distribution of willingness to pay in the population.

The analysis in Figure 1 excludes the choice to switch to carpool to use the HOT lane. Overall, about 6% of respondents said they would shift to carpool, with no clear effect of toll level or time savings on that choice. It is not possible to say how realistic this level of shift is, as many carpools tend to be opportunity-driven, depending on whether another person happens to have a very similar destination and departure time.

With the price meter approach (Method B), we can infer each respondent’s value of time savings (VOT) within a fairly narrow range. The results of that analysis are plotted below, and compared to the distribution from a similar HOT lane survey carried out in Minneapolis (ATL vs. MIN). The distribution function is skewed to the left with a substantial tail to the right, resembling the log-normal distribution, which is typically found for VOT. The distribution has a mode of about $1/hour, a median of about $4.75/hour, and a mean value of about $7.50/hour, slightly lower than the distribution estimated in Minneapolis. The cumulative distribution reaches the 90% point at about $18/hour, meaning that there are 10% of respondents willing to pay more than 3 times the median amount. Less than 1% of respondents are “off the chart,” willing to pay more than $40/hour.

Figure 2. Distribution of Imputed Value of Time

DISTRIBUTION OF IMPUTED VALUE OF TIME

From the willingness to pay distribution above, we can obtain an estimate of the toll revenue at various toll levels, when the toll is expressed in terms of cost per time saved. The resulting curve below gives maximum revenue at a toll of about $7.50 per hour saved. This is the same result as was obtained for Minneapolis, although the revenue is slightly lower for the I-75. If the speed in the general lane were 30 mph, and the speed in the HOT lane were 60 mph, then traveling 1 mile would take 2 minutes in the general lane and 1 minute in the HOT lane, meaning the HOT lane provides a savings of 1 minute per mile. The revenue-maximizing toll would thus be $7.50/60, or 12.5 cents per mile. If, on the other hand, the speed in the general lane were 40 mph, then the HOT lane would only save 0.5 minutes per mile, so the revenue-maximizing toll would only be $7.50/120, or 6.25 cents/mile.

Figure 3. Revenue as a Function of Toll Level

REVENUE AS A FUNCTION OF TOLL LEVEL

DETERMINANTS OF WILLINGNESS TO PAY

To help get an idea what factors cause such a wide distribution in willingness to pay, we analyzed the variation in the average willingness to pay across various market segmentations, using the individual-level values of willingness to pay from Method B. While these results are not very useful for predictive analysis, which is best done based on Logit analysis with the combined responses from both Methods A and B, this simple analysis is useful for understanding the market in terms of what factors have the most influence on willingness to pay, in addition to the standard factors that are usually distinguished in travel models (trip purpose and time of day). The results are explained on the following pages. First, some factors that do NOT appear to have a significant effect on willingness to pay include:

  • Gender
  • Household size
  • Household car ownership
  • Awareness of the plan to put carpool lanes on I-75
  • Trip timing flexibility
  • Direction of travel on I-75 (North or South)
  • Day of week
  • Opinion about charging tolls 24 hours a day
Season

Roughly half of the respondents were surveyed in the summer period of July 14-August 14, while the other half were surveyed during the autumn season of August 15-September 3. Although these two periods are adjoining, a significant difference was found in the willingness to pay, with the average VOT about 10% lower in the latter period ($7.15/hour versus $7.85/hour). This is why the overall average figures reported in this analysis are slightly lower than those reported in the interim analysis done on the summer data only.

Three possible reasons for the somewhat lower values for the autumn period are:

  • Gasoline prices were rising sharply during the period of the survey, and hurricane Katrina disrupted the oil supply during the last week of August, so people may have become more sensitive to travel costs as a result.
  • The people in the latter period reported marginally lower highway congestion levels for their actual trips relative to the earlier period—perhaps due to the fact that many children were back in school.
  • The distribution of household incomes for the latter period sample is somewhat lower than in the sample from the earlier period. This is probably due to random sampling variation.

Figure 4. Average Value of Time Savings by Season

AVERAGE VALUE OF TIME SAVINGS BY SEASON

Income

As is typically found, willingness to pay is clearly related to income, but does not increase proportionally with income. This result indicates that other factors besides income also enter into the decision of whether or not to pay the toll.

Figure 5. Average Value of Time Savings by Income Group

AVERAGE VALUE OF TIME SAVINGS BY INCOME GROUP

Age

Age is also important, with willingness to pay generally decreasing with age, particularly for individuals of retirement age. This probably indicates less hectic schedules once people pass a certain age. The reason for the high willingness to pay for those under 25 is not clear. These tend to be students, who may be reimbursed by their parents.

Figure 6. Average Value of Time Savings by Age

AVERAGE VALUE OF TIME SAVINGS BY AGE

Trip Purpose

Willingness to pay is lowest for shopping, social visit, and entertainment trips and highest for those picking up or dropping off children (only 7 respondents had this trip purpose, however). The average values for other purposes are near the overall average of $7.50/hr.

Figure 7. Average Value of Time Savings by Trip Purpose

AVERAGE VALUE OF TIME SAVINGS BY TRIP PURPOSE

Time Period

The average value of time savings is highest for those making PM peak trips and lowest for those making off-peak trips. The variation is not as substantial as one might expect, because we offered the same levels of time savings to all respondents. In actual situations where much greater time savings are possible during the peak, the toll that people would be willing to pay would be correspondingly higher.

Figure 8. Average Value of Time Savings by Time Period

AVERAGE VALUE OF TIME SAVINGS BY TIME PERIOD

Actual Congestion Level

We do find quite large variation in willingness to pay according to the reported perceived congestion level for the actual trip. It is interesting that this variation is much larger than the peak/off-peak variation in the preceding chart. Two possible explanations for this are (a) there may be a good deal of congestion at off-peak times and congestion levels may be related to geography as well as time of day, and (b) those who are more time-sensitive and willing to pay higher tolls may also notice congestion levels more and have a lower threshold for what they perceive as “congested.”

Figure 9. Average Value of Time Savings by Congestion Level

AVERAGE VALUE OF TIME SAVINGS BY CONGESTION LEVEL

Opinion of HOT lane project

It is interesting that the average willingness to pay for those who think the HOT lanes is a good idea is almost twice as high as for those who think it is a bad idea. This result is reasonable, since people who are willing to pay for faster travel will receive more benefit from the introduction of HOT lanes than those who are not (who would still receive some travel time benefit, but not as much).

Figure 10. Average Value of Time by Opinion of HOT Lane Idea

AVERAGE VALUE OF TIME BY OPINION OF HOT LANE IDEA

Amount of Time Savings Offered

There were three different time savings levels used for the “price meter” SP questions. The graph below shows that the willingness to pay does not rise linearly with the amount of time savings. In other words, it appears that respondents are willing to spend marginally less for each additional minute saved. The average VOT for a savings of 5 minutes is $9.00/hour, meaning that the average person would spend 75 cents to save 5 minutes. The average VOT for a savings of 10 minutes is $7.50, meaning that the average person would spend $1.25 to save 10 minutes, or 50 cents for the second 5 minutes. The average VOT for a savings of 15 minutes is about $6.40, meaning that the average person would spend $1.60 to save 15 minutes, or 35 cents for the last 5 minutes.

Figure 11. Average Value of Time by Amount of Time Saved

AVERAGE VALUE OF TIME BY AMOUNT OF TIME SAVED

Table 2. VOT and Value of Savings

Time Savings VOT Value of Savings Marginal VOT for Added Minutes
5 minutes $9.00 / hr $0.75 / 5 min $0.75 / 5 min. = $9.00 / hr
10 minutes $7.50 / hr $1.25 / 10 min. $0.50 / 5 min = $6.00 / hr
15 minutes $6.40 / hr $1.60 / 15 min. $0.35 / 5 min = $4.20 / hr

REGRESSION MODEL

Finally, all of the variables listed above were included simultaneously in a regression analysis, regressing each respondent’s imputed Value of Time savings from the “Price Meter” responses against a series of 0/1 dummy variables. Most of the effects discussed above remain significant even when analyzed in combination with the other determinants of VOT. Note, however, that the difference between the summer and autumn seasons is not significant when analyzed together with the other variables, suggesting that the difference found between the seasons is due mainly to differences in the composition of the two sub-samples—random and otherwise.

Also note that the R-squared value for the disaggregate regression model is about 0.06, meaning that about 94% of the variance in individual-level willingness to pay cannot be explained by the exogenous explanatory variables. This is a typical and important result, because it means that simply segmenting VOT by trip purpose, time of day, or other observed variables is not adequate to capture the order of magnitude of variance that actually occurs. Models that do not account for such wide variation will tend to overpredict toll lane usage at low toll levels, and underpredict usage at high toll levels.

Table 3. Regression Model Summary

VARIABLE COEFFICIENT T-STATISTIC
Constant $ 6.92 7.52
Time savings of 5 minutes + $ 1.52 2.23
Time savings of 15 minutes - $ 1.12 -1.67
Very congested + $ 1.23 2.04
Not at all congested - $ 1.54 -1.49
AM peak trip + $ 0.29 0.35
PM peak trip + $ 1.21 1.48
Commute trip - $ 1.86 -2.95
Shopping/social/entertainment trip - $ 1.72 -1.72
Age under 35 + $ 3.08 4.06
Age 35 to 44 + $ 1.53 2.31
Age 65 and older - $ 1.33 -0.98
Income $15-25K - $ 1.81 -0.65
Income $25-60K - $ 0.97 -1.34
Income over $125K + $ 1.66 2.38
Season = autumn - $ 0.33 -0.60
R-squared = 0.061

Back to Table of Contents

Appendix A: Summary of Survey Data

The following is a summary of the survey data. The following tables are based on processed and unweighted data.

Table 4. Data Collection Period

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Summer 1 750 50.0
Fall 2 751 50.0
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 5. How Do You Usually Travel on I-75?

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Drive alone 1 1,182 78.7
Drive with other passengers 2 266 17.7
Ride as a passenger in a personal vehicle 3 44 2.9
Ride as a passenger in a vanpool 4 3 0.2
Ride as a passenger in a bus 5 6 0.4
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 6. Houshold Vehicles

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Zero 0 0 0.0
One 1 216 14.4
Two 2 788 52.5
Three 3 312 20.8
Four or More 4 185 12.3
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 7. Household Size

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
One 1 194 12.9
Two 2 542 36.1
Three 3 288 19.2
Four or More 4 477 31.8
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 8. Perceived Congestion in Atlanta

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Major problem 1 1,093 72.8
Moderate problem 2 298 19.9
Minor problem 3 69 4.6
No problem at all 4 477 31.8
Don't know 8 4 0.3
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 9. Awareness of Managed Lane Construction on I-75

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Yes 1 679 45.2
No 2 822 54.8
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 10. What Have You Heard Regarding Construction of I-75 Managed Lanes

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Toll road/lane was going to be built 2 148 21.8
HOV lane was going to be built 3 286 42.1
Committee was considering a change 4 107 15.8
Read information about a toll road/lane 5 72 10.6
Decision to build toll road/lane has been made 6 50 7.4
Other 1 16 2.4
Total 679 100.0

Table 11. Thoughts on Managed (HOT) Lanes

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Good idea 1 698 46.5
Bad idea 2 706 47.0
Don't know 8 97 6.5
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 12. Why Do You Feel This Way (Regarding HOT Lanes)?

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Defeats the purpose 2 199 14.2
Only people in carpool lanes should be rewarded 3 78 5.6
Don't think it's fair 4 60 4.3
Will not help because it will be the same amount of cars 5 173 12.3
Will help reduce the flow of traffic 6 216 15.4
Gives people a better option to shorten trip 7 372 26.5
The state can raise more money 8 88 6.3
Oppose tolls/already taxed/no direct answer 9 98 7.0
Other 1 120 8.5
Total 1,404 100.0

Table 13. Thoughts on Variable Pricing

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Good idea 1 463 30.8
Bad idea 2 914 60.9
Don't know 8 124 8.3
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 13. Thoughts on Variable Pricing

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Good idea 1 463 30.8
Bad idea 2 914 60.9
Don't know 8 124 8.3
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 14. Why Do You Feel This Way (Regarding Variable Pricing)?

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Tolls should be a flat fee/need to anticipate cost 2 485 35.2
Should not charge too much when traffic is light 3 88 6.4
May create more traffic on those lanes 4 82 6.0
Will help bring in more money 5 37 2.7
Gives a good option to either carpool or pay toll 6 168 12.2
Can help reduce the flow of traffic 7 101 7.3
Oppose tolls/already taxed/no direct answer 9 97 7.0
Other 1 319 23.2
Total 1,377 100.0

Table 15. Thoughts on Hours of Operation

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Good idea 1 850 56.6
Bad idea 2 546 36.4
Don't know 8 105 7.0
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 16. Why Do You Feel This Way (Regarding Hours of Operation)?

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Only needs to be at certain hours of the day 2 254 18.2
Could cause lane to be congested 3 47 3.4
More efficient that way/help with congestion 4 293 21.0
Good option to have/flexibility 5 466 33.4
Oppose tolls/already taxed/no direct answer 9 94 6.7
Other 1 242 17.3
Total 1,396 100.0

Table 17. Influences Regarding Use of Managed Lanes

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Reduce your overall travel time 1 621 41.4
Reduce the amount of time you spend in heavy traffic 2 383 25.5
Increase the predictability of your arrival time 3 231 15.4
Increase personal safety while driving in traffic 4 64 4.3
Price of the toll 5 43 2.9
Some other reason? Specify 7 159 10.6
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 18. Day of Reference Trip

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Monday 1 206 13.7
Tuesday 2 232 15.5
Wednesday 3 262 17.5
Thursday 4 280 18.7
Friday 5 362 24.1
Saturday 6 94 6.3
Sunday 7 65 4.3
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 19. Time of Day of Reference Trip

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
AM Peak (6–10) 1 548 36.5
PM Peak (3–7) 2 540 36.0
Non-Peak 3 413 27.5
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 20. Did You Leave at this Particular Time to Avoid Traffic Congestion?

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Yes 1 546 36.4
No 2 953 63.5
Don't know 8 2 0.1
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 21. What Time Would You Have Preferred to Leave if No Traffic Congestion?

CHOICE FREQUENCY PERCENT
0300-0359 2 0.4
0400-0459 2 0.4
0500-0559 6 1.1
0600-0659 40 7.6
0700-0759 124 23.5
0800-0859 110 20.9
0900-0959 53 10.1
1000-1059 10 1.9
1100-1159 5 0.9
1200-1259 5 0.9
1300-1359 8 1.5
1400-1459 11 2.1
1500-1559 19 3.6
1600-1659 50 9.5
1700-1759 60 11.4
1800-1859 16 3.0
1900-1959 2 0.4
2000-2059 2 0.4
2100-2159 1 0.2
2200-2259 1 0.2
Total 527 100.0

Table 22. North or Southbound Travel

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
North 1 639 42.6
South 2 862 57.4
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 23. Trip Purpose

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Commute to or from work or school 1 650 43.3
Work-related 2 315 21.0
Drop off/pick up school age child 3 22 1.5
Shop 4 57 3.8
Visit friends or family 5 93 6.2
Recreational or entertainment activity 6 138 9.2
Something else 7 226 15.1
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 24. Time Respondent Had to be at Destination

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Specific time plus or minus 10 minutes 1 396 40.1
Specific time plus or minus 30 minutes 2 110 11.1
Had more flexibility in the arrival time than that 3 481 48.7
Total 987 100.0

Table 25. Trip Start

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Home 1 923 61.5
Work 2 376 25.0
Other, Specify Place Name 7 202 13.5
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 26. Trip End

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Home 1 416 27.7
Work 2 404 26.9
Other, Specify Place Name 7 681 45.4
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 27. Arrival Time at End Location

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
AM Peak (7–10) 1 421 28.0
PM Peak (3–7) 2 572 38.1
Non-Peak 3 508 33.8
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 28. Mode of Travel

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Driving alone 1 1,089 72.6
Driving with other passengers 2 355 23.7
Riding as a passenger in a personal vehicle 3 501 3.4
Riding as a passenger in a vanpool 4 2 0.1
Riding as a passenger in a bus 5 4 0.3
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 29. Reference Trip Mode

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
SOV 1 1,089 72.6
HOV 2 406 27.0
Vanpool 3 2 0.1
Transit 4 4 0.3
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 30. Number of Adults on Trip

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
One 1 71 17.5
Two 2 274 67.5
Three 3 40 9.9
Four 4 16 3.9
Five 5 3 0.7
Six 6 1 0.2
Seven 7 0 0
Eight 8 1 0.2
Total 406 100.0

Table 31. Number of Children on Trip

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
None 0 287 70.7
One 1 60 14.8
Two 2 38 9.4
Three 3 17 4.2
Four 4 3 0.7
Five 5 0 0
Six 6 1 0.2
Total 406 100.0

Table 32. Total Occupants

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
One 1 6 1.5
Two 2 264 65.0
Three 3 71 17.5
Four 4 46 11.3
Five 5 13 3.2
Six 6 4 1.0
Seven 7 0 0
Eight 8 1 0.2
Nine 9 1 0.2
Total 406 100.0

Table 33. Was Respondent Delayed by Congestion

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Yes 1 877 58.4
No 2 624 41.6
Total 406 100.0

Table 34. Was Respondent Delayed by Congestion

CHOICE FREQUENCY PERCENT
0-5 2 0.2
6-10 17 1.9
11-15 61 6.9
16-20 105 11.8
21-25 89 10.0
26-30 185 20.9
31-35 75 8.5
36-40 102 11.5
41-45 114 12.9
46-50 24 2.7
51-55 3 0.3
56-60 49 5.5
60+ 61 6.9
Total 887 100.0

Table 35. Did Respondent Make Stops on Trip

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Yes 1 199 13.3
No 2 1,302 86.7
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 36. Type of Stop Made

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Pick up/ drop off kids at daycare 1 10 5.0
Pick up / drop off other people 2 13 6.5
Change your mode of travel, like catch of bus 3 1 0.5
Take care of personal business, like shopping 4 147 73.9
Work-related activity 5 9 4.5
Multiple stops for different purposes 6 19 9.5
Total 199 100.0

Table 37. Number of Times Late to Pick Up Child at Daycare

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
None 1 7 70.0
1-5 2 1 10.0
6-9 3 0 0.0
10 or more times 4 2 20.0
Total 10 100.0

Table 38. Satisfaction with the Overall Quality of Travel on I-75 Between I-285 and I-575

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Very satisfied 1 359 23.9
Slightly satisfied 2 450 30.0
Slightly unsatisfied 3 320 21.3
Very unsatisfied 4 366 24.4
Don't Know 8 6 0.4
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 39. Level of Congestion on this Segment of I-75

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Very congested 1 531 35.4
Somewhat congested 2 493 32.8
Slightly congested 3 310 20.7
Or not congested at all 4 167 11.1
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 40. Employment

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Self-employed 1 259 17.3
Employed full or part time 2 999 66.6
Student full or part time 3 37 2.5
Retired 4 129 8.6
Something else 7 77 5.1
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 40. Total Education

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Grade School 1 14 0.9
GED or High School Graduate 2 196 13.1
Some college or vocational education 3 342 22.8
College Graduate 4 677 45.1
Graduate Degree 5 269 17.9
Refused 9 3 0.2
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 41. Ethnicity

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
White or Caucasian 1 1,265 84.3
Hispanic or Latino 2 34 2.3
African-American 3 124 8.3
Asian-American 4 21 1.4
Other 7 37 2.5
Refused 9 20 1.3
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 42. Age

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
18 - 24 1 60 4.0
25 - 34 2 255 17.0
25 - 34 3 411 27.4
45 -54 4 385 25.6
55 - 64 5 261 17.4
65 or older 6 115 7.7
Refused 9 14 0.9
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 44. Household Income

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
$15,000 or less 1 17 1.1
$15,000 to $24,999 2 27 1.8
$25,000 to $34,999 3 51 3.4
$35,000 to $44,999 4 59 3.9
$45,000 to $49,999 5 49 3.3
$50,000 to $59,999 6 154 10.3
$60,000 to $74,999 7 175 11.7
$75,000 to $99,999 8 302 20.1
$100,000 to $124,999 9 177 11.8
Above $125,000 10 312 20.8
Refused 99 178 11.8
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 45. Follow Up Respondent

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Yes 1 1,268 84.5
No 2 233 15.5
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 46. Preferred Mode for Follow Up

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Telephone 1 720 56.8
Mail 2 190 15.0
Email 3 358 28.2
Total 1,268 100.0

Table 47. Gender

CHOICE CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Male 1 841 56.0
Female 2 660 44.0
Total 1,501 100.0

Table 48. County

CHOICE FIPS CODE FREQUENCY PERCENT
Bartow 13015 26 1.7
Cherokee 13057 851 56.7
Cobb 13067 593 39.5
Fulton 13121 15 1.0
Gordon 13129 1 0.1
Paulding 13223 15 1.0
Total 1,501 100.0

Back to Table of Contents

End Note

1 Upon generating the unlisted sample, NuStats requested that MSG match the sample to their listed database and append address information for all matching records. As a result, the 75% of sample records with address information is a mixture of both listed and unlisted sample.

Back to Table of Contents

 

You may need the Adobe Acrobat Reader to view the PDFs on this page.