Office of Operations Freight Management and Operations

3. Empirical Results

3.1 Estimating Regional Elasticities of Demand

Chapter 2 described tests employed to select a geographic division. Based on the tests and empirical results achieved, the project team selected an approach for estimating the elasticity of demand with respect to highway performance. This section describes and reports the results obtained.

The following equation was estimated separately for each region (East, Central, and West), when demand for daily truck traffic is specified as a function of delay and real per capita income growth:

the following expression should read: The log of, parenthesis, AADTT, subscript lowercase c, subscript lowercase t, closed parenthesis, equals lowercase beta, subscript lowercase c, plus lowercase beta subscript one, multiplied by Delay, subscript lowercase c, subscript lowercase t, plus lowercase beta, subscript two, multiplied by Income, subscript lowercase c, subscript lowercase t.Log(AADTTc,t) = βc + β1Delayc,t + β2Incomec,t

where:

AADTT = Average annual daily truck traffic
Delay = Average delay per mile
Income = Real per capita income growth
t = 1993, 1994,… 2003
c = Corridor

the following expression should read: lowercase beta subscript lowercase cβc are corridor-specific constant, or fixed effects, where:

c = 1,…, 16 for East,
c = 1,…, 18 for Central,
c = 1,…, 21 for West

The coefficientthe following expression should read: beta subscript oneβ1 from the log-lin specification of the model above might be transformed into the elasticity coefficient. In calculus notation,the following expression should read: beta subscript oneβ1 can be expressed as

the following expression should read: beta subscript one equals the ratio of d A A D T divided by d Delay, multiplied by the ratio of one divided by A A D T,

And since the elasticity coefficient (elasticity of demand with respect to highway performance-delay) is defined as

the following expression should read: E equals the ratio of d A A D T divided by d Delay. This ratio is multiplied by the ratio of Delay divided by A A D T,

Therefore

the following expression should read: E equals beta subscript one, multiplied by Delay.

The regression results are summarized in Tables 16, 17, and 18 for the East, Central, and West regions, respectively. The models explain a high percentage of variability in freight demand measured by average annual daily truck traffic, at about 79% for the East, 95% for the Central, and about 94% for the West.

The coefficients on the delay and income variable have the correct signs and are statistically significant. The only exception is the coefficient on income in the model for the West region (see Table 18), which is insignificant at the 5% level. However, it is significant at the 10% level.

Table 16. Regression Results for the East Region
Dependent Variable: LOG(AADTT)
Method: Pooled EGLS (Cross-section weights)
Total pool (unbalanced) observations: 114
Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic p-value
Constant 8.847002 0.013168 671.8803 0.0000
Delay -0.005117 0.002344 -2.182555 0.0315
Real Per Capita Income Growth 0.008595 0.004069 2.112079 0.0373
Fixed Effects:
Atlanta-Jacksonville 0.125424      
Atlanta-Knoxville 0.323139      
Atlanta-Mobile -0.233984      
Birmingham-Nashville -0.232907      
Columbus-Pittsburgh -0.054241      
Harrisburg-Philadelphia 0.012104      
Mobile-New Orleans -0.259956      
Richmond-Philadelphia 0.44495      
Boston-New York City 0.032609      
Harrisburg-New York City 0.154785      
Detroit-Pittsburgh -0.104274      
Philadelphia-New York City -0.106916      
New York City-Cleveland 0.037953      
Miami-Richmond -0.261302      
Miami-Atlanta -0.176157      
Knoxville-Harrisburg 0.297654      
R-squared 0.78757 Mean dependent var 8.856317
Sum squared resid 1.534467 Durbin-Watson stat 1.020177

Table 17. Regression Results for the Central Region
Dependent Variable: LOG(AADTT)
Method: Pooled EGLS (Cross-section weights)
Total pool (unbalanced) observations: 138
Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic p-value
Constant 8.745927 0.011244 777.8526 0.0000
Delay -0.069076 0.019921 -3.467458 0.0007
Real Per Capita Income Growth 0.00866 0.003502 2.473205 0.0148
Fixed Effects:
Cleveland-Columbus 0.187098      
Dayton-Detroit 0.127923      
Indianapolis-Chicago 0.176353      
Indianapolis-Columbus 0.345631      
Kansas City-St Louis 0.192902      
Knoxville-Dayton 0.322572      
Louisville-Columbus 0.231423      
Louisville-Indianapolis 0.198499      
Nashville-Louisville 0.598196      
Nashville-St Louis -0.398262      
St Louis-Indianapolis 0.189179      
Omaha-Chicago 0.01184      
Chicago-Cleveland -0.206494      
Billings-Sioux Falls -1.651534      
Amarillo-Oklahoma City 0.142811      
Memphis-Dallas 0.373809      
Memphis-Oklahoma City 0.165234      
St Louis-Oklahoma City -0.349393      
R-squared 0.948179 Mean dependent var 8.744014
Sum squared resid 2.002249 Durbin-Watson stat 1.010586

Table 18. Regression Results for the West Region
Dependent Variable: LOG(AADTT)
Method: Pooled EGLS (Cross-section weights)
Total pool (unbalanced) observations: 129
Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic p-value
Constant 8.370945 0.011247 744.2735 0.0000
Delay -0.015586 0.00573 -2.720287 0.0076
Real Per Capita Income Growth 0.005534 0.003323 1.665585 0.0987
Fixed Effects:
Dallas-Houston 0.533012      
San Antonio-Houston 0.335623      
Denver-Kansas City -0.672123      
Denver-Salt Lake City 0.044107      
San Francisco-Salt Lake City -0.632347      
San Francisco-Los Angeles 0.247815      
Portland-Seattle 0.668379      
San Diego-Los Angeles 0.544992      
Seattle-Billings -0.6264      
Seattle-Sioux Falls -0.867802      
Portland-Salt Lake City -0.276968      
Los Angeles-Tucson 0.097899      
Tucson-San Antonio 0.557139      
Laredo-San Antonio -0.06466      
Nogales-Tucson 0.28696      
San Antonio-Dallas 0.669072      
Barstow-Bakersfield 0.257096      
Barstow-Amarillo 0.105583      
Barstow-Salt Lake City -0.156777      
Galveston-Dallas 0.343733      
Dallas-El Paso 0.198615      
R-squared 0.940778 Mean dependent var 8.377655
Sum squared resid 1.913074 Durbin-Watson stat 0.776213

The semi-logarithmic functional form of the estimated equations requires the coefficients on the delay variable to be transformed in order to interpret them in elasticity terms. Table 19 shows this step and provides a summary of findings regarding the impact of changes in delay on freight demand.

Table 19. Implied Elasticity of Demand for Three Regions
Region Coefficient on Delay Implied Elasticity Interpretation
East -0.005117 -0.0076 Other things being equal, a 10% increase in delay per mile reduces freight demand by 0.07%.
Central -0.069076 -0.0175 Other things being equal, a 10% increase in delay per mile reduces freight demand by 0.175%.
West -0.015586 -0.0070 Other things being equal, a 10% increase in delay per mile reduces freight demand by 0.07%.

3.2 Calculating Regional Additive Freight Reorganization Benefits

3.2.1 Microeconomic Framework

Figure 4 gives a diagrammatic representation of the microeconomic framework which identifies the benefits of industrial reorganization. Area A represents the immediate benefits of a highway improvement to existing highway users (principally user time savings and reduced vehicle operating costs). Area B represents the immediate benefits accruing to users newly attracted to the highway by virtue of the improvement. Areas A and B together represent the benefits conventionally measured in a CBA.

Area C represents the value of efficiency gains to the economy due to industrial reorganization precipitated by the highway improvement. Industrial reorganization means the adoption of advanced logistics the firm's business case for which depend on the likelihood of a threshold level of reliability in highway performance. Defined as the ratio of area C to the sum of areas A and B namely,the following expression should read: C divided by the sum of A plus BC/[A+B] expressed as a percentage, the "additive freight reorganization benefit" gives the percentage by which to increase the value of conventionally-measured benefits to freight traffic in order to approximate total benefits. In other words, the benefits inclusive of the reorganization effect.

Figure 4
Figure 4. Change in Consumer Surplus from Changing Demand for Transportation as a Function of Unit Generalized Transportation Cost

To assess the quantitative significance of the additive reorganization benefit, the study amassed quantitative evidence of the following:

the following expression should read: uppercase Q subscript zeroQ0: Initial demand for freight transportation (vehicle-miles (vm));
the following expression should read: uppercase Q subscript oneQ1: New demand level as a result of highway improvements or policy change;
the following expression should read: uppercase C subscript zeroC0: Initial unit generalized cost of transportation ($/vm);
the following expression should read: uppercase C subscript oneC1: New unit generalized cost of transportation ($/vm) following highway improvement or policy change; and
the following expression should read: lowercase beta subscript zeroβ0 the following expression should read: lowercase beta subscript oneβ1 Immediate and post-reorganization slopes of the transport demand curves (respectively) with respect to the generalized cost of transportation, where generalized cost is the linear sum of vehicle operating expenses, delay-related expenses and unreliability-related expenses.

As discussed in the Phase II report on the national analysis, a variable-elasticity form of the present and post-reorganization demand curves (indicating constant returns to scale) provides a reasonable description of the available data. Specifically, the elasticity of demand for transport with respect to generalized cost is found to vary proportionately with generalized cost. This means that the elasticity is smaller when generalized cost is relatively low, and it is higher when generalized cost is relatively high, implying that demand is more sensitive to changes in highway conditions when congestion is high than when congestion is low. The form of the estimated demand curve is:

the following expression should read: natural logarithm of uppercase Q equals lowercase beta subscript zero plus lowercase beta subscript one multiplied by uppercase CLn Q = β0 + β1 * C

where Q is the quantity of transportation that would be demanded at a generalized cost of C, and wherethe following expression should read: lowercase beta subscript zeroβ0 andthe following expression should read: lowercase beta subscript oneβ1 are constants estimates with least-squares in a fixed-effects model that controls for between-corridor variations.

3.2.2 Additive Benefit Calculation Module

The additive benefit estimation module has been developed to accommodate outcomes from two broad categories of cost benefit analysis models: 1) standard user cost models, where the practitioner focuses on the reduction of user costs to existing highway users (baseline transportation demand, as measured by truck vehicle miles traveled (VMT) or other metrics) and ignore induced demand (additional highway trips brought about by the reduction in transport costs); and 2) consumer surplus models, where the practitioner explicitly accounts for induced demand using standard transportation demand elasticity estimates and estimates the change in consumer surplus resulting from a candidate highway investment.

Additive Benefit Estimation with Standard User Cost Models

In Figure 5, the additive benefit would be estimated as the ratio of indirect benefits, represented by the red triangle B (the area between the long run transport demand curve and thethe following expression should read: C subscript oneC1 line, and bounded bythe following expression should read: V M subscript zeroVM0 andthe following expression should read: V M subscript oneVM1), to direct benefits, represented by the blue rectangle A (the area between thethe following expression should read: C subscript zeroC0 andthe following expression should read: C subscript oneC1 lines and to the left ofthe following expression should read: V M subscript zeroVM0).

the following expression should read: Additive Benefit Factor equals Area B divided by Area AAdditive Benefit Factor = Area B / Area A

With the application of the additive benefit factor, direct benefits (or benefits to existing highway users) are augmented to represent total benefits (direct plus indirect benefits). Total benefits within this framework are measured by the change in consumer surplus using the long-run demand curve for freight.

Figure 5
Figure 5. Additive Benefit Estimation with Standard User Cost Models, An Illustration

A numerical example of additive freight reorganization benefit estimation is provided in Table 20.

Table 20. Additive Benefit Estimation with Standard User Cost Models, A Numerical Example
# Parameters Value Comments
Unit Generalized Costs ($/vehicle mile)
1 the following expression should read: uppercase C subscript zeroC0 $3.8100 Assumption / input.
2 the following expression should read uppercase C subscript oneC1 $3.4351 Assumption (10% reduction).
Transport Demand (freight vehicle miles)
3 the following expression should read: uppercase V M subscript zeroVM0 200,000 Assumption / input.
4 the following expression should read: uppercase V M subscript oneVM1 220,434* Calculated using the nominal elasticity (b).
Demand Curve
5 Constantthe following expression should read: lowercase a equals uppercase V M subscript zero multiplied by the term uppercase C subscript zero raised to power lowercase b(a = VM0*C0 raised to power b) 49,879  
6 Full Price Elasticity (b) -1.0382*  
7 the following expression should read: lowercase r equals one minus the dividend of one over lowercase br = 1-(1/b) 1.9632 Estimation of area below demand curve and betweenthe following expression should read: uppercase V M subscript zeroVM0 andthe following expression should read: uppercase V M subscript oneVM1.
8 the following expression should read: lowercase a raised to the power of the dividend of one over lowercase ba^(1/b) 2.98484E-05
9 the following expression should read: the term lowercase a raised to the power of the dividend of one over lowercase b multiplied by the term open parentheses the term uppercase V M subscript one raised to power lowercase r minus the term uppercase V M subscript zero raised to power lowercase r close parentheses divided by lowercasse ra^(1/b) * ((VM1^r)-(VM0^r))/r 81,679
10 the following expression should read: uppercase Delta uppercase V M multiplied by uppercase C subscript oneDelta VM * C1 70,191 Estimation of area D.
11 the following expression should read: uppercase V M subscript zero multiplied by uppercase Delta uppercase CVM0 * Delta C 74,988 Estimation of area A.
12 Direct Benefits (Row 11) $74,988 User cost savings.
13 Indirect Benefits (Row 9 minus Row 10) $11,487 Estimation of area B (triangle).
14 Total benefits (Row 12 + Row 13) $86,476 Area A + B.
15 % Indirect / Direct 15.3%* The additive benefit factor.

*Numbers in red signify key variables that illustrate the change in demand.

The full price elasticity (b) on row 6 is estimated by considering the combined impact of the elasticity of demand with respect to out-of-pocket costs (direct vehicle operating costs or shipping rate) and a measure of the long-run elasticity of demand with respect to highway performance (transit time and reliability).

For the purpose of this study, the elasticity of freight demand with respect to transportation costs was derived from the literature (-0.97, Tae Oum). The long-run elasticity of demand with respect to highway performance was estimated econometrically, as part of Phase II and Phase III of the study.

Additive Benefit Estimation with Consumer Surplus Models

In Figure 6, the additive benefit factor would be calculated as the ratio of area F (the area between the long-run transport demand curve "with reorganization effects," the standard short run demand curve, and thethe following expression should read: C subscript oneC1 line) to a standard measure of consumer surplus, represented by area A plus area E.

the following expression should read: Additive Benefit Factor equals Area F divided by the sum of Area A and Area EAdditive Benefit Factor = Area F / (Area A + Area E)

In other words, the additive benefit factor is estimated as the percentage change in consumer surplus resulting from incremental transport demand along the long-run demand curve. Incremental transport demand is illustrated by the shift fromthe following expression should read: V M subscript oneVM1 tothe following expression should read: V M subscript twoVM2 on Figure 6.

Figure 6
Figure 6. Additive Benefit Estimation with Consumer Surplus Models, An Illustration

A numerical example of additive benefit estimation with consumer surplus models is provided in Table 21.

Table 21. Additive Benefit Estimation with Consumer Surplus Models, A Numerical Example
# Parameters Standard Consumer Surplus Model Output Augmented Output and Additive Benefit Estimation
Unit Generalized Costs ($/vehicle mile)
1 the following expression should read: uppercase C subscript zeroC0 $3.8100 $3.8100
2 the following expression should read uppercase C subscript oneC1 $3.4351 $3.4351
Transport Demand (freight vehicle miles)
3 the following expression should read: uppercase V M subscript zeroVM0 200,000 200,000
4 the following expression should read: uppercase V M subscript oneVM1 219,400* 220,434*
Demand Curve
5 Constantthe following expression should read: lowercase a equals uppercase V M subscript zero multiplied by the term uppercase C subscript zero raised to power lowercase b(a = VM0*C0 raised to power b) 54,642 49,879
6 Full Price Elasticity (b) -0.9700* -1.0382*
7 the following expression should read: lowercase r equals one minus the dividend of one over lowercase br = 1-(1/b) 2.0309 1.9632
8 the following expression should read: lowercase a raised to the power of the dividend of one over lowercase ba^(1/b) 1.30602E-05 2.98484E-05
9 the following expression should read: the term lowercase a raised to the power of the dividend of one over lowercase b multiplied by the term open parentheses the term uppercase V M subscript one or two raised to power lowercase r minus the term uppercase V M subscript zero raised to power lowercase r close parentheses divided by lowercasse ra^(1/b) * ((VM1 or 2^r)-(VM0^r))/r 77,614 81,679
10 the following expression should read: uppercase Delta uppercase V M multiplied by uppercase C subscript oneDelta VM * C1 66,641 70,191
11 the following expression should read: uppercase V M subscript zero multiplied by uppercase Delta uppercase CVM0 * Delta C 74,988 74,988
12 Direct Benefits (Row 11) $74,988 $74,988
13 Indirect Benefits (Row 9 minus Row 10) $10,973 $11,487
14 Total benefits (Row 12 + Row 13) $85,962 $86,476
15 % change in "total benefits"   0.60%*
16 % change in "indirect benefits"   4.7%*

*Numbers in red signify key variables that illustrate the change in demand.

Discussion

Both approaches may be developed for the Phase III tool so that analysts not estimating user costs prior to calculator use would still be able to calculate an additive freight reorganization benefit factor. A review of current CBA approaches suggests that most analysts would likely use the Consumer Surplus approach.

In both models, the calculation is sensitive to the difference between current and anticipated demand (AADTT) and user costs, which are items that will vary project to project. It is proposed that the model also calculate the transformation of the elasticity on a project-by-project basis, factoring in the existing delay on the segment being improved. This would also add variability and local specificity to the additive benefit calculation.

Both approaches will be further assessed and refined as part of Phase III-B.

3.2.3 Regional Additive Benefit Factors

The process of computing the additive benefit factor, explained above, was then applied to the three regions of interest. Each region is defined by its elasticities of demand with respect to performance and price.

Table 22 shows the regional elasticities of demand with respect to highway performance estimated through regression analysis in earlier steps.

Table 22. Elasticity of Demand with Respect to Highway Performance
Region Implied Elasticity
East -0.0076
Central -0.0175
West -0.007

Several difficulties were encountered in Phase II for the development of price elasticity. Both price and demand elasticity are required for the estimation of an additive benefit factor. One acknowledged and accepted value for price elasticity (derived from estimates by Tae Oum in a national analysis is currently used for each of the three corridors. Therefore the value of -.97, as estimated by Tae Oum, is used here. However, an attempt was made to regionalize this value as follows:

Table 23. Elasticity of Demand with Respect to Price
U.S. Regional Differences* When Compared to the National Level (-0.97 = 100%) Regional Estimate of Elasticity of Demand with Regard to Price
  East 115.3% East -1.12
-0.97 Central 99.6% Central -0.97
  West 86.9% West -0.84

*Note: The regional differences were derived using a proxy variable for which regional data were available. The proxy variable, in this case, is the average V/C ratio. Relating the V/C ratio to the elasticity of demand with respect to price is based upon two assumptions:

  1. The high level of congestion is an indicator of high-level economic activity.
  2. The demand for transportation with respect to price is more elastic in areas with a higher-level economic activity.

Using the two elasticities presented above and the computer model described above, sample regional additive benefit factors were calculated, as shown in Table 24. These represent an additive benefit factor for the typical corridor in each regional sample and are provided as an illustration of the additional freight benefits would have been for the average corridor in each region.

Each corridor developing a logistics benefit estimation will derive a unique additive benefit factor based on certain regional and national characteristics:

  • Regional elasticity
  • Price elasticity

And certain corridor-specific characteristics:

  • AADTT
  • Delay
  • Predicted traffic demand
  • User costs
  • Calculated freight benefits
Table 24. Regional Additive Benefit Factors
Region East Central West
Additive Benefit Factor 16.7% 14.8% 12.7%

3.2.4 Commodity Flow Data Analysis

Analysis of FAF commodity flow data was conducted for the East, Central, and West regions. Data available included top commodities by volume (weight) and by value. The data describe regional mixes of freight movement that are similar but not the same.

From a value perspective, finished and semi-finished goods rank high in the mix of goods in each region; however, the specific goods vary by region. Except for the Central region, finished goods were not significant contributors of freight volume. In the Central region, machinery and motorized vehicles were the ninth and tenth largest categories of shipment by volume.

Tables 25 and 26 present the top commodities by thousand tons and dollar value. This greater than average volume of finished and semi-finished goods in the Central region may explain the higher than average elasticity of demand with respect to highway performance in the region.

Table 25. Top Commodities Transported in Three Regions (Thousand Tons)
Region Commodity Thousand Tons
East Gravel 7,173.3
Waste/scrap 5,999.1
Cereal grains 5,110.0
Other foodstuffs 4,083.3
Unknown 3,956.9
Nonmetal mineral products 3,576.3
Wood prods. 3,154.3
Mixed freight 3,024.1
Base metals 2,916.3
Nonmetallic minerals 2,322.5
Central Base metals 2,866.0
Nonmetal mineral products 2,480.8
Gasoline 2,013.9
Other foodstuffs 1,795.7
Mixed freight 1,621.7
Unknown 1,587.5
Waste/scrap 1,471.8
Gravel 1,385.6
Machinery 1,164.6
Motorized vehicles 1,115.2
West Nonmetal mineral products 14,739.6
Gravel 7,703.2
Gasoline 7,593.5
Coal, n.e.c. 4,344.5
Mixed freight 3,707.7
Other foodstuffs 3,488.1
Unknown 3,415.4
Wood prods. 3,136.2
Natural sands 2,623.0
Waste/scrap 2,491.3

Table 26. Top Commodities Transported in Three Regions ($Million)
Region Commodity $M
East Mixed freight 11,824
Machinery 10,247
Motorized vehicles 6,054
Textiles/leather 5,047
Pharmaceuticals 4,891
Other foodstuffs 4,399
Electronics 3,951
Printed prods. 3,788
Unknown 3,690
Misc. manufacturing products 3,457
Central Machinery 7,420
Mixed freight 6,568
Motorized vehicles 5,306
Base metals 2,672
Pharmaceuticals 2,618
Electronics 2,159
Articles-base metal 1,907
Misc. manufacturing products 1,877
Other foodstuffs 1,826
Plastics/rubber 1,623
West Mixed freight 17,672
Machinery 13,279
Electronics 13,224
Motorized vehicles 8,732
Other foodstuffs 5,366
Textiles/leather 5,303
Chemical prods. 4,811
Articles-base metal 4,807
Gasoline 4,582
Misc. manufacturing products 4,322

previous | next
Office of Operations